In the spring of 2019, over 50 wealthy parents in the United States were charged in a shocking college admissions scandal, with many of them currently facing jail time and hefty fines.1 The parents, who included famous actresses such as Lori Loughlin and Felicity Huffman, were accused of bribing college officials to admit their children into elite universities; Felicity Huffman, for instance, gave SAT invigilators $15,000 USD to give her daughter extra time on the exam, while another parent offered the women’s soccer coach at Yale received $400,000 to recruit their unqualified daughter to the team.2 This scandal not only painted a grim image of corruption in the U.S. education system, but also provides us with an interesting behavioral question: Why were these college officials willing to risk it all when presented with an illegal bribe?
Of course, this scandal was just one specific and well-known example of corruption. It is not uncommon these days to hear news of corruption in sectors such as government, business, and sport. The willingness to accept bribes and engage in corrupt behavior is something that has occurred throughout history worldwide, with clear detrimental effects on economic growth, inequality, the environment, and more.3 In fact, across the globe an estimated $1.75 trillion USD is exchanged in the form of bribes each year.4 That is an extraordinary amount. To put this number into perspective, this sum is equivalent to the entire nominal GDP of Canada, the tenth-largest economy in the world.5 Clearly, corruption is a topic of global importance and we must try to better understand why people are willing to engage in it in order to reduce it.
However, studying corruption is incredibly difficult for one clear and obvious reason: corruption is illegal. Officials who engage in corruption do so in secret, and as a result, it’s difficult to get accurate data on this phenomenon.
Les sciences du comportement, démocratisées
Nous prenons 35 000 décisions par jour, souvent dans des environnements qui ne sont pas propices à des choix judicieux.
Chez TDL, nous travaillons avec des organisations des secteurs public et privé, qu'il s'agisse de nouvelles start-ups, de gouvernements ou d'acteurs établis comme la Fondation Gates, pour débrider la prise de décision et créer de meilleurs résultats pour tout le monde.
Corruption in the lab
The typical approach that researchers have used to study corruption is through observational studies, which use cross-country data and subjective indexes of corruption.6 Although these studies are important for understanding the economic, social, and cultural factors which determine corruption, they do not provide us with much insight on the behavioral reasons for why officials engage in corruption.
One relatively new approach that behavioral scientists have taken to study corruption is through controlled laboratory experiments. Experiments allow researchers to simulate the environment in which corrupt decisions are made, in order to directly observe participants’ responses to various anti-corruption interventions. This is effective if we wish to, for example, test the effects of a potential anti-corruption policy on specific behavioral responses, as experiments generate hard data that can answer very specific questions. This can all be done in a relatively cost-effective manner too, as compensating participants is usually the only significant financial investment required to run an experiment. All of this makes experiments a cheap, preliminary diagnostic tool for anti-corruption policies before they are implemented in the real world.
The behavioral causes of corruption
The power of reciprocity
Perhaps unsurprisingly, one obvious reason why officials would act unethically is because of money. If offered a substantial bribe, officials would be willing to face all the risks and the costs involved with the illicit activity in order to receive a sizeable reward.
But corruption does not just revolve around money. There are also psychological factors at play in the typical corrupt transaction. Think about it: A briber undertakes a substantial amount of risk when they approach an official for an illegal favor. The official could refuse to take the bribe, they could notify the authorities, or they could even accept the bribe and not go through with the favor. But why is it that in real life, plenty of officials are willing to not only accept bribes, but also follow through with the favor?
The answer lies in our innate desire to reciprocate the kindness of others. Reciprocity is a social norm that explains why we feel inclined to be kind to those who are kind to us (and cruel to those who are cruel to us).7 It can explain many phenomena that are difficult to account for using standard economic theory, which assumes people are selfish and rational—for example, why waitresses who smile more earn higher tips, or why we are willing to buy something from the salesperson who gave us a free sample.8,9
When reciprocity fuels corruption
Reciprocity is something that is typically considered prosocial: when we reciprocate the kindness of others, we are abiding by the social norm. But our desire to reciprocate is actually a major reason behind corruption, something that is obviously not pro-social. This is because an official may perceive a bribe as a kind gesture, and by reciprocating, they would simply be behaving in a way that is deemed socially acceptable. After all, the briber was generous enough to go through the trouble of not only approaching the official, but also offering them money.
Of course, by following through with the favor, the official is neglecting societal interest, since this favor generally has great benefits to the briber but detrimental consequences to the public. This therefore depicts a fascinating behavioral component of corruption: our desire to reciprocate seemingly overrides our greater sense of morality and causes officials to engage in corruption.
A 2002 study by Abbink, Irlenbusch, and Renner tested this idea through a pioneering experimental bribery game that simulated a typical corruption scenario, in which participants acted as either a potential briber or a public sector official.10 They found that a large proportion of officials routinely reciprocated the trust of bribers by choosing the corrupt course of action, despite having no contractual obligations to do so. Officials could have been better off materially had they simply accepted the bribe and not gone through with the corrupt action, but it was precisely because of reciprocity motivations that they chose the corrupt option instead.
In addition, when the authors introduced negative externalities to the experiment, even though bribers and officials fully understood that their participation in a transaction had adverse effects on other participants in the experiment, corruption persisted.11 Apparently, the knowledge that your actions would harm others was not enough to curb the urge to reciprocate.
We value reciprocity over collective good
These findings capture a disheartening picture of human nature, but it is also quite unsurprising given that people act corruptly in real life despite often having knowledge of the consequences. But why do people continue to engage in corruption even though they know full well that their behavior harms many innocent people? Are people really that selfish?
Perhaps the answer lies in the fact that the effects of corruption are often felt by an unobservable group of people. Behavioral biases such as the identifiable victim effect demonstrate that people feel less empathy for large, vaguely-defined groups of people than for a specific, identifiable individual.12,13 For example, you are likely to feel a greater sense of empathy when you hear the story of Jimmy, a 12-year-old boy in Africa who is dying of starvation, than when you hear the statistic that over 26 million children are starving in Africa.
This could be a potential explanation for why officials are undeterred by the negative externalities of corruption. Even though officials know their actions have harmful consequences, the effects are felt by a large, unobservable group of people, while the officials are unlikely to feel the burden themselves. This behavior can be likened to other harmful actions such as littering: we all know that littering has negative effects on the environment, but because we do not feel the burden ourselves or see the impacts directly, we do not feel the necessity to stop.
Behavioral solutions to corruption
So far, we have discussed how lab experiments can simulate the corruption decision environment to uncover certain aspects of corrupt behavior, but experiments can also effectively test anti-corruption interventions.
We can classify the potential solutions for corruption into two broad categories: extrinsic motivations and intrinsic motivations. Behavior that is extrinsically motivated is driven by external incentives, such as money or power; meanwhile, intrinsically motivated behavior is done for its own sake.14
Extrinsic motivation: A different kind of bribe
Most experiments to date have investigated the extrinsic motivations behind corruption, and have focused on altering external incentives to reduce it. These studies have proposed solutions such as introducing harsher penalties for those caught in corruption,15 increasing monitoring (for example, through increased audits),16 raising the wages that officials earn,17,18 rotating staff more frequently, and requiring that multiple officials be involved when making important decisions.20
Reframing corruption
One fundamental drawback to these extrinsic motivation solutions is that they are often costly to implement. This may make them relatively unattractive for policymakers. On the other hand, focusing on intrinsic motivation as an anti-corruption strategy could be a more cost-effective solution. Since corruption is generally considered morally unacceptable, researchers have also examined ways in which we can induce feelings of guilt or shame in order to reduce corrupt behavior from occurring.
These studies primarily involve framing corruption in an immoral light (for example, by using the loaded phrase “private payment” in experiments instead of the neutral “transfer”) and/or making the negative externalities of corruption more salient (or noticeable) to try and generate an emotional response nudge people away from corruption.21,22,23
By changing the language around corruption, participants may become more aware of their own dishonesty and subsequently refrain from behaving fraudulently. Although this approach is still in its infancy, these studies can provide insights into how policymakers should frame their messages, and what information they should emphasize, when designing anti-corruption awareness campaigns.
Using reciprocity: Building trust
Other approaches that have been suggested in this domain include promoting trust between employers and public officials. Companies and governments often force workers to sign compliance forms and sit through anti-corruption workshops, all of which can create a spirit of distrust. As we know, people have an innate desire to reciprocate, so perhaps the solution may be for leaders to have more faith in their workers and treat them better.24 This way, workers may feel intrinsically obliged to reciprocate the employer’s kindness and always act honestly.
How useful are corruption experiments?
You may argue that lab experiments cannot capture real-world corruption accurately, since the fact that participants know they are being watched may bias their decision-making (see the observer expectancy effect).25 The external validity of economic laboratory experiments is a common critique of experimental economics in general, where critics often argue that lab experiments may not be reflective of real-world decisions which typically depend on many unobservable factors.26 For the topic of corruption, however, there has been evidence to suggest the results from the lab experiments do have real-world validity. For example, one group of researchers managed to replicate their lab experiment findings in a field experiment where participants were unaware that they were participating in an experiment.27 This research provided evidence that lab experiments can capture some of the key motives behind real-life corruption behavior and have external validity.
Takeaways: Leveraging reciprocity
Behavioral science has grown to become extremely influential in the development of policies in recent years, and these experimental corruption studies provide another example of their usefulness. Through the innovative methods researchers have developed, we are now able to study a complex, unobservable phenomenon in a powerful and cost-effective way. And despite this being a relatively new field of study, several effective solutions have already appeared in the literature (with many of which not mentioned in this article). Of course, behavioral approaches are not, and should not, be the only approach we should use to analyze corruption, but they are another tool that we can utilize to understand this phenomenon better.
References
1. McLaughlin, K. (2020). Here’s everyone who has been sentenced in the college admissions scandal so far. Insider. Retrieved 11 December 2020, from https://www.insider.com/college-admissions-scandal-full-list-people-sentenced-2019-9.
2. Durkin, E. (2019). US college admissions scandal: how did the scheme work and who was charged?. the Guardian. Retrieved 11 December 2020, from https://www.theguardian.com/us-news/2019/mar/12/college-admissions-fraud-scandal-felicity-huffman-lori-loughlin.
3. Serra, D., & Wantchekon, L. (2012). New Advances in Experimental Research on Corruption (pp. 77-114). Emerald Group Publishing Limited.
4. Corruption Statistics. Transparency International UK. n.d. Retrieved 11 December 2020, from https://www.transparency.org.uk/corruption-statistics.
5. Silver, C. (2020). The Top 20 Economies in the World. Investopedia. Retrieved 11 December 2020, from https://www.investopedia.com/insights/worlds-top-economies/.
6. Abbink, K., Irlenbusch, B., & Renner, E. (2002). An Experimental Bribery Game. Journal Of Law, Economics, And Organization, 18(2), 428-454. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/18.2.428
7. Social Norms. The Decision Lab. Retrieved 19 December 2020, from https://thedecisionlab.com/biases/social-norms/.
8. Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity. Journal Of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159-181.
9. Tidd, K. L., & Lockard, J. S. (1978). Monetary significance of the affiliative smile: A case for reciprocal altruism. Bulletin of the Psychonomic Society, 11(6), 344-346.
10. Abbink, K., Irlenbusch, B., & Renner, E. (2002). An Experimental Bribery Game. Journal Of Law, Economics, And Organization, 18(2), 428-454. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/18.2.428
11. Abbink, K., Irlenbusch, B., & Renner, E. (2002). An Experimental Bribery Game. Journal Of Law, Economics, And Organization, 18(2), 428-454. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/18.2.428
12. Identifiable Victim Effect. The Decision Lab. Retrieved 21 December 2020, from https://thedecisionlab.com/biases/identifiable-victim-effect/.
13. Jenni, K., Loewenstein, G. (1997) Explaining the Identifiable Victim Effect. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 14, 235–257. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1007740225484
14. Cherry, K. (2020). Extrinsic vs. Intrinsic Motivation: What’s the Difference?. Verywell Mind. Retrieved 11 December 2020, from https://www.verywellmind.com/differences-between-extrinsic-and-intrinsic-motivation-2795384.
15. Abbink, K., Irlenbusch, B., & Renner, E. (2002). An Experimental Bribery Game. Journal Of Law, Economics, And Organization, 18(2), 428-454. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/18.2.428
16. Serra, D. (2011). Combining top-down and bottom-up accountability: Evidence from a bribery experiment. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization. doi: 10.1093/jleo/ewr010
17. Abbink, K. (2005). Fair salaries and the moral costs of corruption. Proceedings of the Conference on Cognitive Economics, Sofia.
18. Van Veldhuizen, R. (2013). The influence of wages on public officials’ corruptibility: A laboratory investigation. Journal of economic psychology, 39, 341-356.
19. Abbink, K. (2004). Staff rotation as an anti-corruption policy: An experimental study. European Journal of Political Economy, 20, 887–906.
20. Schickora, J. T. (2011a). Bringing the four-eye-principle to the lab. Discussion Paper No. 2011-3. Department of Economics, University of Munich.
21. Framing effect. The Decision Lab. Retrieved 11 December 2020, from https://thedecisionlab.com/biases/framing-effect/.
22. Salience Bias. The Decision Lab. Retrieved 21 December 2020, from https://thedecisionlab.com/biases/salience-bias/.
23. Barr, A., & Serra, D. (2009). The effects of externalities and framing on bribery in a petty corruption experiment. Experimental Economics, 12(4), 488–503.
24. Graf Lambsdorff, Johann (2015) : Preventing corruption by promoting trust: Insights from behavioral science, Passauer Diskussionspapiere – Volkswirtschaftliche Reihe, No. V-69-15, Universität Passau, Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Fakultät, Passau
25. Observer Expectancy Effect. The Decision Lab. Retrieved 21 December 2020, from https://thedecisionlab.com/biases/observer-expectancy-effect/
26. Levitt, S. D., & List, J. A. (2007). What do laboratory experiments measuring social preferences reveal about the real world?. Journal of Economic perspectives, 21(2), 153-174.
27. Armantier, O., & Boly, A. (2011). A controlled field experiment on corruption. European Economic Review, 55(8), 1072-1082.